globalchange  > 全球变化的国际研究计划
DOI: doi:10.1038/nclimate2874
论文题名:
Designer policy for carbon and biodiversity co-benefits under global change
作者: Brett A. Bryan
刊名: Nature Climate Change
ISSN: 1758-680X
EISSN: 1758-6800
出版年: 2015-11-30
卷: Volume:6, 页码:Pages:301;305 (2016)
语种: 英语
英文关键词: Climate-change policy ; Ecosystem services ; Biodiversity ; Climate-change mitigation
英文摘要:

Carbon payments can help mitigate both climate change and biodiversity decline through the reforestation of agricultural land1. However, to achieve biodiversity co-benefits, carbon payments often require support from other policy mechanisms2 such as regulation3, 4, targeting5, 6, and complementary incentives7, 8. We evaluated 14 policy mechanisms for supplying carbon and biodiversity co-benefits through reforestation of carbon plantings (CP) and environmental plantings (EP) in Australias 85.3 Mha agricultural land under global change. The reference policy—uniform payments (bidders are paid the same price) with land-use competition (both CP and EP eligible for payments), targeting carbon—achieved significant carbon sequestration but negligible biodiversity co-benefits. Land-use regulation (only EP eligible) and two additional incentives complementing the reference policy (biodiversity premium, carbon levy) increased biodiversity co-benefits, but mostly inefficiently. Discriminatory payments (bidders are paid their bid price) with land-use competition were efficient, and with multifunctional targeting of both carbon and biodiversity co-benefits increased the biodiversity co-benefits almost 100-fold. Our findings were robust to uncertainty in global outlook, and to key agricultural productivity and land-use adoption assumptions. The results suggest clear policy directions, but careful mechanism design will be key to realising these efficiencies in practice. Choices remain for society about the amount of carbon and biodiversity co-benefits desired, and the price it is prepared to pay for them.

Market-based incentives are important policy mechanisms for managing land use and ecosystem services9 and can influence land-use decisions by changing price signals or transaction costs in existing markets, or by creating new markets. Carbon markets are a contemporary example of market-based incentives and many have emerged at national and sub-national levels10. Other major payment schemes (for example, Chinas Grain for Green programme11, Costa Ricas Payment for Ecosystem Services12, the United Statess Conservation Reserve Program, Australias Emissions Reduction Fund, and the international REDD+ mechanism13) also incentivize the reforestation of cleared land. Although these schemes often prioritize carbon sequestration, there are strong interactions with other environmental goals, especially biodiversity conservation5, 13, 14.

Many factors can influence the cost-effectiveness (relative value-for-money) and efficiency (degree to which they achieve maximum value-for-money) of policy mechanisms in delivering carbon and biodiversity co-benefits9, 15. Payment design can substantially affect the efficiency of carbon markets13, 16, 17. Regulation (such as land-use planning, safe minimum standards, and codes of practice) is often used to limit trade-offs18, but may reduce efficiency through imposing uniform practices. Payment targeting5, 14 and the use of complementary incentives such as premium payments7, 8, 13 can both increase biodiversity co-benefits. Although the efficiency and cost-effectiveness of policy mechanisms have been assessed for achieving a range of environmental objectives19, 20 including carbon and biodiversity co-benefits7, 21, evaluations have been limited to single mechanisms and/or undertaken for pilot projects at local scales. Large-scale, quantitative, comparisons of multiple mechanisms are rare22. No evaluations have considered global change, despite the necessity of evidence-based policy that is robust to future uncertainty23.

We evaluated the ability of policy mechanisms to supply carbon sequestration and biodiversity co-benefits through reforestation of CP and EP under global change using the LUTO (Land-Use Trade-Offs) model7, 24. Although CP (fast-growing Eucalyptus monocultures) provide only carbon benefits, EP (mix of native trees and shrubs) provide both carbon and biodiversity co-benefits. Land-use change was determined by economic competitiveness. We evaluated 12 core policy mechanisms (Fig. 1), combinations of two payment schemes (uniform and discriminatory) implemented as reverse auctions, two land-use policies (competition and regulation), and three payment targeting strategies (carbon, biodiversity, and multifunctional). The total costs and benefits of these policy mechanisms were quantified under four global outlooks at levels equivalent to the 2050 carbon price. Sensitivity was assessed at three agricultural productivity and land-use change adoption rates (Table 1). Then for a common budget, the cost-effectiveness and efficiency of policy mechanisms were compared against the reference policy, which was consistent with a carbon market price (U–C–C, see Fig. 1 for key), and a Pareto efficiency frontier representing the maximum joint production of carbon and biodiversity co-benefits achievable for a given budget. We also evaluated the ability of two incentives complementing the reference policy to cost-effectively increase the supply of biodiversity co-benefits. The incentives included a biodiversity premium providing additional targeted payments for EP achieving a 15% biodiversity target consistent with the Convention on Biological Diversity Aichi Target 15, and a 10% carbon levy imposed on CP revenues with the funds used for biodiversity premium payments for EP. Results are presented for 2050 under M3 Central—the M3 global outlook with medium agricultural productivity and adoption hurdle rate settings (that is, M 2×)—with the sensitivity analysis in the Supplementary Results.

Figure 1: Supply of, and trade-offs between, carbon sequestration and biodiversity co-benefits for different policy mechanisms.
Supply of, and trade-offs between, carbon sequestration and biodiversity co-benefits for different policy mechanisms.

ad, Supply curves for the 12 core policy mechanisms for M3 Central, with supply curves for all four global outlooks, including sensitivity to agricultural production and adoption behaviour assumptions, presented in Supplementary Figs 1–20. e, Trade-offs between carbon sequestration and biodiversity co-benefits for each policy under M3 Central given a common budget equal to that of the reference policy (U–C–C, AUD$292 billion). The Pareto efficiency frontier (dark dotted line) identifies the maximum carbon and biodiversity co-benefits achievable for the budget and the trade-offs between them. White numbers within marker symbols indicate the total area of reforestation in Mha (CP + EP). aUniform payments with land-use competition and regulation targeting biodiversity were equivalent, with both coded U–CR–B. bDiscriminatory payments with land-use competition and regulation targeting biodiversity were equivalent, with both coded D–CR–B. Colours in the legend relate to all panels.

Policy mechanisms.

Supplementary Table 5 details the payment schemes, land-use policy, targeting strategies, and complementary incentives assessed in this study.

Study area and policy settings.

This analysis was undertaken for the entire intensive agricultural land of Australia—a non-contiguous area of privately owned and managed cleared land stretching across eastern and southern Australia from Queensland to southwest Western Australia (Supplementary Fig. 21). We do not consider potential land-use change in native vegetation, wetland/riparian, or urban areas.

Agricultural policy in Australia has long been focused on increasing agricultural productivity and competitiveness, and has included relatively low levels of public subsidy. Recent climate policy has included both a price on carbon and direct payments, and bipartisan support exists for land sector contribution to climate change mitigation31. Australian biodiversity policy has included many individual incentive schemes for enhancing biodiversity on private land32, 33, 34.

Global outlooks and sensitivity.

We addressed multiple uncertainties using both scenario analysis and sensitivity analysis. To capture the uncertainty in global environmental and economic conditions, we assessed four global outlooks for the period 2013 to 2050 (Supplementary Table 6). Developed through a series of stakeholder interviews and workshops25, outlooks are internally consistent, plausible futures defined by different settings for global action on greenhouse gas emissions abatement, the size of the world economy and human population, and the degree of radiative forcing. Outlooks are benchmarked to the Representative Concentration Pathways35 (RCPs). Integrated assessment was undertaken using the Global Integrated Assessment Model25, 36 to provide projections of key parameters affecting the economic competitiveness of land use including demand for crops and livestock and prices for carbon and oil (Supplementary Fig. 22).

We undertook a sensitivity analysis across variation in agricultural productivity and land-use change adoption behaviour27 (Table 1). Three simple annual increases in agricultural total factor productivity were considered encompassing the range of increases experienced between 1977/1978–2007/08 in Australia37, with the high rate representing a step change increase in productivity. Uncertainty in land-use change adoption behaviour by landholders was captured by three hurdle rates covering the range of variation reported in the land-use change literature38, 39, 40, 41, 42. Thus, most calculations were performed under each global outlook o, adoption hurdle rate h, and agricultural productivity rate u.

Model pre-calculations.

The core analysis involved substantial spatio-temporal, integrated environmental–economic modelling using the Land-Use Trade-Offs model7, 24. The analyses were undertaken using ~1.1-km-resolution raster data (812,383 grid cells) and an annual temporal resolution. Spatio-temporal modelling was conducted with Python43 and NumPy (ref. 44). Model parameters and mathematical notation are summarized in Supplementary Table 7. Bold notation indicates a spatial layer, represented as a vector of grid cells, each with their own individual value for the parameter. Mathematical operations involving spatial layers occurred elementwise (grid cell by grid cell) unless indicated by square brackets, which symbolize operations occurring over all grid cells.

Climate change.

Future climate change estimates were modelled at ~1.8° grid cell resolution using a pattern regression process45 based on the outputs of the MPI-ESM-LR general circulation model (GCM). These change estimates were used to modify high-resolution, ANUCLIM-interpolated spatial layers of annual mean climate (rainfall and temperature) to create future climate layers for each global outlook. Carbon sequestration and dryland agricultural yields were projected under each global outlook on the basis of regressed relationships with annual mean temperature and rainfall7. Estimates of changes in water scarcity were also made on the basis of the climate change modelling and used to modify water prices over time.

Carbon sequestration.

We considered carbon stored in accumulated plant biomass following reforestation as our measure of carbon sequestration in metric tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (denoted tCO2), and did not include changes in soil carbon or agricultural emissions. We used 3-PG2-modelled spatial layers of the 20-year carbon sequestration potential (tCO2 ha−1) for mixed environmental carbon plantings and hardwood carbon plantings46 to model carbon sequestration by EP and CP, respectively. This was converted to 100-year carbon accumulation layers and a growth curve was used to model annual carbon sequestration over time7. Carbon sequestration was adjusted for climate change under global outlooks7 and reduced by 20% to account for risk. Carbon sequestration for both reforestation land uses f in F{CP, EP} under the four global outlooks o was calculated as the average annual climate- and risk-adjusted rate over the 100-year period multiplied by grid cell area a.

Biodiversity co-benefits.

Biodiversity co-benefits accruing from the establishment of EP were estimated from a continuous biodiversity layer7 produced using a generalized dissimilarity model47. The model related plant species compositional turnover between 325,459 site pairs, including over 12,000 species of vascular plants, to environmental layers including 11 downscaled, terrain-adjusted climate metrics and 12 soil and substrate metrics at 0.01° spatial resolution. Compositional turnover was then predicted for each grid cell in response to a change between present-day climate (climatic averages for 1985–2005) and six 2050 climate futures—combinations of two climate scenarios (RCP 4.5 and RCP 8.5) and three GCMs (Can ESM2, MPI ESM2, and MIROC5). The extent to which EP in each grid cell would increase the representation of vascular plant communities requiring similar environmental conditions within a 1,000km radius was calculated. Higher biodiversity co-benefits were obtained in grid cells that best increase the representation of plant communities under future climate change and have greater landscape connectivity as determined by proximity to remnant habitat and species–area relationships7. The final, single biodiversity priority score layer Bf was a weighted average of the six climate scenario/GCM combinations calculated using the limited degree of confidence approach48 and, hence, is robust to uncertainty in future climate change and remains constant over time.

The generic term biodiversity co-benefits Bsf refers to the sum of the area a of each grid cell multiplied by the biodiversity layer Bf, divided by the sum of this calculation over all grid cells. Bsf was expressed as a percentage of the maximum possible biodiversity co-benefits achievable by reforesting all agricultural land with EP.

There are several sources of uncertainty in the biodiversity co-benefits of reforestation. Although both monoculture plantings and agricultural land may provide ecological benefits49, the benefits of CP relative to EP are uncertain and likely to be low. Hence, we assumed that Bsf = 0 for f = CP. However, in practice, uncertainty also exists in the biodiversity co-benefits from EP. Many habitat resources take decades to develop (for example, tree hollows, fallen boughs, and so on) and many species need to be actively introduced owing to a lack of local populations50. Tree plantings may even have adverse effects on biodiversity if they replace native grasslands and shrublands or diverse farmland assemblages, or where monocultures preclude future biodiversity co-benefits from active or natural reforestation.

Economic returns.

Economic returns to agriculture were calculated on an annual basis in 2010 Australian dollars as profit at full equity (the economic return to land, capital, and management, exclusive of financial debt) using a profit function51, 52, 53, 54. Economic returns were calculated for a set of 23 irrigated and dryland agricultural commodities mapped by ABARES (ref. 55) for the 2005/06 agricultural census year. Yields and commodity prices were sourced from agricultural census data56, fixed and variable cos

URL: http://www.nature.com/nclimate/journal/v6/n3/full/nclimate2874.html
Citation statistics:
资源类型: 期刊论文
标识符: http://119.78.100.158/handle/2HF3EXSE/4508
Appears in Collections:全球变化的国际研究计划
科学计划与规划
气候变化事实与影响
气候变化与战略

Files in This Item: Download All
File Name/ File Size Content Type Version Access License
nclimate2874.pdf(588KB)期刊论文作者接受稿开放获取View Download

Recommended Citation:
Brett A. Bryan. Designer policy for carbon and biodiversity co-benefits under global change[J]. Nature Climate Change,2015-11-30,Volume:6:Pages:301;305 (2016).
Service
Recommend this item
Sava as my favorate item
Show this item's statistics
Export Endnote File
Google Scholar
Similar articles in Google Scholar
[Brett A. Bryan]'s Articles
百度学术
Similar articles in Baidu Scholar
[Brett A. Bryan]'s Articles
CSDL cross search
Similar articles in CSDL Cross Search
[Brett A. Bryan]‘s Articles
Related Copyright Policies
Null
收藏/分享
文件名: nclimate2874.pdf
格式: Adobe PDF
此文件暂不支持浏览
所有评论 (0)
暂无评论
 

Items in IR are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.